The two pieces that follow, from
Martin Wolf of the Financial Times and Michael
Feller of Macro Strategists, explore the implications of a new paper by Robert
Gordon on the limits to growth.
Wolf:
Might growth be ending? This is a
heretical question. Yet an expert on productivity, Robert Gordon of
Northwestern university, has raised it in a provocative paper. In this, he
challenges the conventional view of economists that “economic growth ... will
continue indefinitely.”
Yet unlimited growth is a heroic
assumption. For most of history, next to no measurable growth in output per
person occurred. What growth did occur came from rising population. Then, in
the middle of the 18th century, something began to stir. Output per head in the
world’s most productive economies – the UK until around 1900 and the US,
thereafter – began to accelerate. Growth in productivity reached a peak in the
two and a half decades after World War II. Thereafter growth decelerated again,
despite an upward blip between 1996 and 2004. In 2011 – according to the
Conference Board’s database – US output per hour was a third lower than it
would have been if the 1950-72 trend had continued (see charts). Prof Gordon
goes further. He argues that productivity growth might continue to decelerate
over the next century, reaching negligible levels.
The future is unknowable. But the
past is revealing. The core of Prof Gordon’s argument is that growth is driven
by the discovery and subsequent exploitation of specific technologies and –
above all – by “general purpose technologies”, which transform life in ways
both deep and broad.
The implementation of a range of
general purpose technologies discovered in the late 19th century drove the
mid-20th century productivity explosion, Prof Gordon argues. These included
electricity, the internal combustion engine, domestic running water and
sewerage, communications (radio and telephone), chemicals and petroleum. These
constitute “the second industrial revolution”. The first, between 1750 and
1830, started in the UK. That was the age of steam, which culminated with the
railway. Today, we are living in a third, already some 50 years old: the age of
information, whose leading technologies are the computer, the semiconductor and
the internet.
Prof Gordon argues, to my mind
persuasively, that in its impact on the economy and society, the second
industrial revolution was far more profound than the first or the third. Motor
power replaced animal power, across the board, removing animal waste from the
roads and revolutionising speed. Running water replaced the manual hauling of
water and domestic waste. Oil and gas replaced the hauling of coal and wood.
Electric lights replaced candles. Electric appliances revolutionised
communications, entertainment and, above all, domestic labour. Society
industrialised and urbanised. Life expectancy soared. Prof Gordon notes that
“little known is the fact that the annual rate of improvement in life
expectancy in the first half of the 20th century was three times as fast as in
the last half.” The second industrial revolution transformed far more than
productivity. The lives of Americans, Europeans and, later on, Japanese, were
changed utterly.
Many of these changes were
one-offs. The speed of travel went from the horse to the jet plane. Then, some
fifty years ago, it stuck. Urbanisation is a one-off. So, too, is the collapse
in child mortality and the tripling of life expectancy. So, too, is control
over domestic temperatures. So, too, is liberation of women from domestic
drudgery.
By such standards, today’s
information age is full of sound and fury signifying little. Many of the
labour-saving benefits of computers occurred decades ago. There was an upsurge
in productivity growth in the 1990s. But the effect petered out.
In the 2000s, the impact of the
information revolution has come largely via enthralling entertainment and
communication devices. How important is this? Prof Gordon proposes a
thought-experiment. You may keep either the brilliant devices invented since
2002 or running water and inside lavatories. I will throw in Facebook. Does
that make you change your mind? I thought not. I would not keep everything
invented since 1970 if the alternative were losing running water.
What we are now living through is
an intense, but narrow, set of innovations in one important area of technology.
Does it matter? Yes. We can, after all, see that a decade or two from now every
human being will have access to all of the world’s information. But the view
that overall innovation is now slower than a century ago is compelling.
What does this analysis tell us?
First, the US remains the global productivity frontier. If the rate of advance
of the frontier has slowed, catch-up should now be easier. Second, catch-up
could still drive global growth at a high rate for a long time (resources
permitting). After all, the average gross domestic product per head of
developing countries is still only a seventh of that of the US (at purchasing
power parity). Third, growth is not just a product of incentives. It depends
even more on opportunities. Rapid increases in productivity at the frontier are
possible only if the right innovations occur. Transport and energy technologies
have barely changed in half a century. Lower taxes are not going to change
this.
Prof Gordon notes further obstacles
to rising standards of living for ordinary Americans. These include: the
reversal of the demographic dividend that came from the baby boomers and
movement of women into the labour force; the levelling-off of educational
attainment; and obstacles to the living standards of the bottom 99 per cent.
These hurdles include globalisation, rising resource costs and high fiscal
deficits and private debts. In brief, he expects the rise in the real
disposable incomes of those outside the elite to slow to a crawl. Indeed, it
appears to have already done so. Similar developments are occurring in other
high-income countries.
For almost two centuries, today’s
high-income countries enjoyed waves of innovation that made them both far more
prosperous than before and far more powerful than everybody else. This was the
world of the American dream and American exceptionalism. Now innovation is slow
and economic catch-up fast. The elites of the high-income countries quite like
this new world. The rest of their population like it vastly less. Get used to
this. It will not change.
Feller summarizes the Gordon paper as well, citing Wolf, but
then goes on to offer a range of fascinating connections in the history of
economic thought:
These are questions others have
asked as well, ranging from the longue durée historians of the Sorbonne, who
are attempting to pinpoint capitalism’s demise by 2100 (economic systems, like
those of feudal Europe or the Roman Empire, apparently last 600 years), to UBS
strategist Andy Lees, who last year provocatively claimed the world had hit its
innovation peak in the 1840s.
Furthermore, these questions are
not new. William Morris, better known for his wallpaper designs, wrote of a
cashless society in late Victorian England. In 1516, philosopher Thomas More
described the isle of Utopia where gold and silver were cast aside for pursuits
of real prosperity, the metals only used for the “humblest items of domestic
equipment”.
And of course, there was John
Stuart Mill, who in 1848 would advance the notion of the ‘stationary state’,
where objectives of economic quality were to be pursued over objectives of
economic quantity. This no-growth model would later have appeal for Kibbutzniks,
survivalists, and environmentalists such the authors of the 1972 Club of Rome
report – who reintroduced Mill’s concept of the limits of growth to a new
Malthusian audience. Even John Meynard Keynes, an admirer of Mill, would at
times lament the obsession politicians would come to have with GDP, an
instrument of measurement he helped devise for limited use during the Second
World War.
Yet Mill’s legacy is perhaps most
relevant today with global populations now stabilising, the risks of catastrophic
climate change becoming ever more apparent, technology supplanting labour and
productivity seen by many economists as the last great hope for growth. Indeed,
outside of canonising modern liberalism or the idea of falsification in the
scientific method, Mill’s most important contribution to political economy was
arguably his theory of development: that growth was a function of capital,
labour and land (or natural resources). Mill felt that sustainable development
was only possible if growth in labour was exceeded by growth in land and
capital productivity, rather than debt. With middle class wages stagnating and
the so-called 99% seeing few of the economic gains that we are supposed to have
made since the economic deregulation of the 1980s, Mill’s dictums speak a
remarkable truth across the gulf of time.
In a week where prominent fund
manager Bill Gross likened America’s credit-based economic model to a crystal
meth addiction (like any ‘hopium’ or narcotic, debt borrows the benefits of
tomorrow for the enjoyment of today) and when central banks, from Australia to
Russia, are joining peers in Europe, Britain, the US and Japan in pushing down
rates or pump-priming markets with liquidity, one can see another of Mill’s
classic warnings – the tyranny of the majority – coming true, with quick fixes
and short-term solutions the order of the day.
Yet no country is as perhaps as apt
for Mill’s analysis than China: a country that is in a self-imposed demographic
decline, where utilitarianism and capital factor productivity have been warped
into a fixed-asset bubble and where land is quite literally denuded of soil,
drained of moisture and acidified by the detritus of industrialisation.
In an oped for the New York Times
last week, economist Richard Easterlin described China’s belief it could
purchase social stability through rapid economic growth as a “Faustian
bargain”; a phrase also used recently by Bundesbank chief Jen Wideman’s in
criticising the European Central Bank’s outright monetary transactions.
In a survey of opinions on life
satisfaction scored between 1990 and 2011, Easterlin and his colleagues found
that the average Chinese is no more satisfied today than they were in the
aftermath of Tiananmen Square. Moreover,
scores on satisfaction for urbanites actually declined for most of the period,
as old social safety nets – China’s so-called ‘iron rice bowl’ – were removed
in the name of productivity, efficiency and, ultimately, economic
liberalisation, and as the competitive urges of capitalism overtook the cooperation,
forced as it was or not, of socialism.
Yet unlike other post-Enlightenment
political philosophies – both the capitalism of Adam Smith or the communism of
Karl Marx – Mill saw growth as more than material. Borrowing from its classical
antecedent – the Ancient Greeks spoke of humanity’s goal aseudaimonia, or
flourishing – modern society is built on the ideal of improvement, development,
growth and expansion, but it needn’t be so mono-dimensional. Indeed, Aristotle
considered an essential pillar of eudaimonia, or one of the four cardinal
virtues, to be moderation.
The problem is that in many ways we
may have already reached the limits of growth. Politicians like to talk about
half-glass full and half-glass empty, yet ultimately we’re still drinking from
the same poisoned chalice. By relooking at John Stuart Mill there may be a more
refreshing alternative.
* * *
The one thing that neither writer focuses on—and a very big
thing it is—is the implications of the limits to growth on our debt-bound
economies. Adjustment to the end of growth would be far easier in the absence
of the debt overhang. Growth as usual threatens the environment, it may be
ventured, but the end of growth threatens to crash the entire financial
architecture.
* * *
Martin
Wolf, “Is unlimited growth a thing of the past,” Financial Times, October 2, 2012
Michael
Feller, “What if the GFC [Global Financial Crisis] is permament,”
macrobusiness.com.au
Robert
J. Gordon, “Is U.S. Economic Growth Over? Faltering Innovation Confronts the
Six Headwinds,” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No 18315
(August 2012).
No comments:
Post a Comment