The extracts below, about 10% of the entry on Ecological Economics at Wikipedia, emphasize a series of contrasts with the dominant
neoclassical approach embedded in “environmental economics.”
Ecological economics is referred to
as both a transdisciplinary and interdisciplinary field of academic research
that aims to address the interdependence and coevolution of human economies and
natural ecosystems over time and space. It is distinguished from environmental
economics, which is the mainstream economic analysis of the environment, by its
treatment of the economy as a subsystem of the ecosystem and its emphasis upon
preserving natural capital. One survey of German economists found that
ecological and environmental economics are different schools of economic
thought, with ecological economists emphasizing "strong"
sustainability and rejecting the proposition that natural capital can be substituted
by human-made capital. . . .
According to ecological economist
Malte Faber, ecological economics is defined by its focus on nature, justice,
and time. Issues of intergenerational equity, irreversibility of environmental
change, uncertainty of long-term outcomes, and sustainable development guide
ecological economic analysis and valuation. Ecological economists have
questioned fundamental mainstream economic approaches such as cost-benefit
analysis, and the separability of economic values from scientific research,
contending that economics is unavoidably normative rather than positive
(empirical). Positional analysis, which attempts to incorporate time and
justice issues, is proposed as an alternative. . . .
Some ecological economists prioritize
adding natural capital to the typical capital asset analysis of land, labor,
and financial capital. These ecological economists then use tools from
mathematical economics as in mainstream economics, but may apply them more
closely to the natural world. Whereas mainstream economists tend to be
technological optimists, ecological economists are inclined to be technological
sceptics. They reason that the natural world has a limited carrying capacity
and that its resources may run out. Since destruction of important
environmental resources could be practically irreversible and catastrophic,
ecological economists are inclined to justify cautionary measures based on the
precautionary principle. . . .
While this natural capital and
ecosystems services approach has proven popular amongst many it has also been
contested as failing to address the underlying problems with mainstream
economics, growth, market capitalism and monetary valuation of the environment.
Critiques concern the need to create a more meaningful relationship with Nature
and the non-human world than evident in the instrumentalism of shallow ecology
and the environmental economists commodification of everything external to the
market system. . . .
Ecological economics is
distinguishable from neoclassical economics primarily by its assertion that the
economy is embedded within an environmental system. Ecology deals with the
energy and matter transactions of life and the Earth, and the human economy is
by definition contained within this system. Ecological economists argue that
neoclassical economics has ignored the environment, at best considering it to
be a subset of the human economy.
The neoclassical view ignores much
of what the natural sciences have taught us about the contributions of nature
to the creation of wealth e.g., the planetary endowment of scarce matter and
energy, along with the complex and biologically diverse ecosystems that provide
goods and ecosystem services directly to human communities: micro- and
macro-climate regulation, water recycling, water purification, storm water regulation,
waste absorption, food and medicine production, pollination, protection from
solar and cosmic radiation, the view of a starry night sky, etc. . . .
The potential for the substitution
of man-made capital for natural capital is an important debate in ecological
economics and the economics of sustainability. There is a continuum of views
among economists between the strongly neoclassical positions of Robert Solow
and Martin Weitzman, at one extreme and the ‘entropy pessimists’, notably
Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen and Herman Daly, at the other.
Neoclassical economists tend to
maintain that man-made capital can, in principle, replace all types of natural
capital. This is known as the weak sustainability view, essentially that every
technology can be improved upon or replaced by innovation, and that there is a
substitute for any and all scarce materials.
At the other extreme, the strong
sustainability view argues that the stock of natural resources and ecological
functions are irreplaceable. From the premises of strong sustainability, it
follows that economic policy has a fiduciary responsibility to the greater
ecological world, and that sustainable development must therefore take a
different approach to valuing natural resources and ecological functions. . . .
A key idea of ecological economics is conveyed in the
following figure, also from Wikipedia, which shows the “three nested systems of
sustainability”—the economy is wholly contained by society, and both are wholly
contained by the biophysical environment.
No comments:
Post a Comment